Resource allocation in strategic factors

Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 1
RESOURCE ALLOCATION IN STRATEGIC FACTORS
Student’s Name
Course
Professor’s Name
University
City (State)
Date
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 2
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors
Backgrounds of “Real Options Theory”
The “Real Options Theory” (ROT) starts via developing a comparison amid the financial
alternatives and the real choices. By definition, financial alternative connote the derivative
security that has its value retrieved from the characteristics and the worth of a second or
alternative financial security, or asset. Financial option offers its investors with the right, and
does not give an obligation, to sell or buy the said asset as at a directive price (for instance, an
exercise price) before/on a stated date (for instance, the date of expiration). Scholes & Black
(1973) as well as Merton (1973), the then great financial economists, created the financial option
valuation formula, and their respective methodologies have led to the subsequent studies
regarding the financial asset pricing, which the resulted in the creation and advancement of the
ROT (Smit & Trigeorgis, 2004).
The perception that the real options were created from Meyer’s seminal concept which can be
perceived as company’s optional investment chances as calls on the real assets, in similar ways
as financial options call gives the decisions rights on the financial assets (1997). Through
analogy, the real options have their own unique underlying assets of the value of the gross
project of the anticipated operating/working cash flows; the real options exercise prices are the
investment needed to get this mentioned asset; the maturity time is the time taken when the
maker of the decision can have the investment deferred before the expiry of the investment
decision (Trigeorgis, 1996). Earlier identified, the “real options” describe the reserves in the
“real assets”, not as in “financial assets” case that confers the company freedom, as opposed to
the duty, to pursue particular steps in the near period (like in Trigeorgis, 1996; Amram &
Kulatilaka, 1999). The “real options” and “financial options” comparisons can be found in a
general textbook (Brealey et al., 2006).
The research on real options in economics and finance fields has advanced a categorization of
similar “real options” which are most of the time attached in an investment, and this include
stage investment options, differed options, options to change the operating scale, options to
position investment, switching options, growth options, and abandonment options (Trigeorgis,
1993). Additionally, an investment frequently entails a mixture of a selected number of the
common “real options” mentioned earlier, and their summed-up worth usually fluctuates from
total of the value of every option on its own. Investments like venture capital and development of
a new technology may also constitute sequential steps, and such investments involving multiple
stages constitutes multiple choices, whose intentioned asset is not basically “real asset”, but
instead a different type of alternative (Trigeorgis, 1996). To the level which some financiers has
the ability to simultaneously hold options, company undertaking several investments at option
time may also undergo interactions of the option portfolio, in the embedded options in a single
investment may help in shaping the other options value which are held by the company and as a
result the option portfolio anticipated value (Luehrman, 1998).
The literature regarding real options in the fields of finance and economics do seem to feature
analytic direction, involving analysis of real options to evaluate a company’s investment under
some improbability as well as to create the optimum situations and settings for pursuing the
investment (Roberts & Weitzman, 1981). For instance, earlier research studies have evaluated
investments in flexible manufacturing and natural resource (Triantis & Hodder, 1990; Brennan &
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 3
Schwartz, 1985), studied the optimal timing and estimation of investment in the land
development portfolio, and looked into the relationship and association between the value of the
company and the option to change operating scale (Titman, 1985, Majd & Pindyck, 1989
McDonald & Siegel, 1985; Pindyck, 1988). Dixit (1992) and Pindyck (1991) looked into the
literature about investing 8nder uncertainty, while Dixit and Pindyck (1994) explored massive
literature on theoretical advances. Earlier studies have paid more attention to the competitive
environment that surrounds the company’s investing and their strategic concept of real options,
which bears critical effect for competitive strategy (Grenadier, 2000; Smit & Trigeorgis, 2004;
Kulatilaka & Perotti, 1998). Earlier researchers have also concentrated on “real options theory”
to study investments in the creating and developing strategic resources like R&D, together with
other corporate innovations like diversification and acquisitions, in the broader angle of
corporate strategy (Pacheco-de-Almeida & Zemsky, 2003; Matsusaka, 2001; Bernardo &
Chowdhry, 2002; Childs & Triantis, 1999; Matsusaka, 2001).
There are relatively very few empirical studies that have considered theoretical work in literature
in the field in large scale. This has been indicated by Schwartz and Trigeorgis (2001) in their
study. The existing scientific studies that have delved in real options in the economics and
finance sector have largely focused on the analytical area of natural investment and development
in real estate (Moel & Tufano, 2002; Quigg, 1993; Paddock, Siegel, & Smith, 1988). The studies
have also investigated the impact and insinuations of specific possibilities for the worth of the
company (Berger, Ofek, & Swary, 1996). Scientific studies regarding the corporate development
and strategic resources are not sufficient, however, and implementation matters of options
associated to the company, incentives, etc. are yet to be done in depth.
Development of ROT in Strategic Management
The original attentiveness and focus on “real option” in strategic management areas started to
surface around the 1980s (Hayes & Garvin, 1982; Trigeorgis, 1996). This occurred when the
scholars in the field of management first expressed lack of satisfaction with the conventional
financial methods like NPV (net present value) to strategic decision-making processes and in the
resource allocation. These methods make it a little more difficult and challenging to account for
follow-up on the rare opportunities in investment which re always embedded in the corporate
investment cases, or to attract the flexibility of the managers in adapting or implementing their
decisions to technological uncertainties and the evolving market, a view also supported by Kester
(1984) and Myers (1984).
Kogut, an economist expert was amongst the first scholars to take time and conceptualize and to
scientifically test the “real options” accordingly in strategic management arena. Kogut’s seminal
works began in regards to the MNCs as well as the synchronization/cooperation of their tasks
and maneuvers in different republics across the world. Kogut, in a number of scientific articles,
maintained that the MNC (the multinational corporations) operations confer them a series of
“real options” to dominate on the greater heights of heterogeneous in addition to uncertain
occasions that are present in different nations. For example, Kogut fronted the suggestion that
investment in the international platform confers MNCs valuable and very profitable options for
growth and the very first outlay in an overseas state provides an outsized option worth because
the investment can unravel raft of prospects for impending growth. The author likewise
expounded that the multinationals hold a selection of substituting the available preferences that
provide suppleness in operations via permitting the company to change value chain undertakings
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 4
over different geographical detached affiliates of the main company since uncertain
environmental events and conditions improve and evolve.
Figure: Strategic Management Real Options Research Framework
There are several studies that have done further studies on Kogut’s initial contributions to the
sector in a number of significant ways. For example, Kogut & Kulatilaka (1994a) created a
framework that monitors and measures the value of option of production changing between tow
country geographical areas in the existence of highly volatile exchange rates. In another study,
Kogut and Chang (1996) scientifically conducted scientific tests of the concept that the very first
investment (initial) may serve as the base for the concurrent enlargement, and they revealed that
the direct investment by Japanese companies in the United States were originated or prompted by
an increase of the Japanese currency. In their research, Miller and Reuer (1998a, b) looked at the
multinationals in their US economic exposure to the movements of the foreign exchange rate.
They proved that companies having greater FDIs featured lower exposures and that these kinds
of exposures were basically asymmetric that is in tandem with the existence of “real options”. In
their part, Allen & Pantzalis (1996) and Tang and Tikoo (1999) proved the appreciation and
valuation of the depth of multinational corporations’ international operations by the stock
market, giving support to the perception that switching options is viable to the companies. Reuer
et al., in recent study embedded the importance of functioning with ease and flexibility in regards
to the downside risk minimization from the MNC reserves (Tong & Reuer, 2007; Reuer &
Leiblein, 2000). The scientists suggested that the level to which the multinationals can benefit
from the operations in different geographical boundaries interferes with some organizational
factors that increase switching costs and coordination.
The pioneering contributions by Kogut also constituted the areas of organizational and
governance options in corporate strategy area (Kogut, 1991). The scholar issued the very first
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 5
theoretical foundations and arguments and the scientific evidence that the joint ventures gives
companies real options to grow sequentially into uncertain and totally new markets. Through
investing in a joint venture, a company is in position to expand, but only on the condition that the
future turns out to be favourable. Congruent to the theory, the author discovered that the
companies undertake expansion by practising the option through purchasing of its partner when
the combined endeavor undergoes a constructive demand stock, but the organization go on to
hold onto the cooperative undertaking investment when undesirable demand indicators shows.
A good number of empirical and theoretical studies that later emerged has looked to go further
length by studying the organizations’ choice in a specific governance mode and related
governance design matters (Chi & McGuire, 1996). First, adopting the formal frameworks, Chi
et al., looked into the situations and conditions under which to sell or acquiring a joint venture
gives positive financial value for the trading partners. They looked into the circumstances under
which an organization might hold the options privileges, and the scrutinized governance
configuration concerns, for instance, the equity market allocations amid the associates (Chi,
2000). Reuer et al. examined the real options attached to the different types of joint ventures and
their findings showed that joint ventures improve an organizations progression option values,
and under certain special identified situations.
Secondly, Folta (1998) investigated the companies’ decisions to pursue joint ventures versus
acquisitions through viewing the joint ventures as giving the sequential commitments and
deferral option. The scientist discovered that the corporations have a high probability of
investing in the joint ventures as compared to acquisition when experiencing high levels of
uncertainty in its operations. In their research, the scholars Folta and Miller (2002) furthered
study based on Kogut’s (1991) study putting their emphasis on the decisions regarding option
exercise. The scientists also went further to examine the minority investments. Folta et al went
further to continue on his earlier study (Folta, 1998) and to further on Dixit and Pindyck’s (1994)
research. They focus on the deferral options, looking at company’s market entry choices in their
study, and gave consistent results with the “real options theory” (Folta, Johnson, & O’Brien,
2006; Folta & O’Brien, 2004; Miller and Folta, 2002). Collectively, the entire group of research
studies has started to gear towards real options theory of organizational governance and market
entry option that have the ability to effectively complement the currently prevailing principles:
the market entry frameworks, vary in their qualities and the attached options as they take a
diverse way of responding to uncertainty, thereby making companies to use them in a
discriminate manner to build and structure their respective investments.
During the same period that Kogut did his experiments, Bowman and Hurry (in the years 1987
and 1993) were also tirelessly doing their best to create option theory based on strategic
management angle. The two authors proposed option to be a strategy heuristic that is important
for a clear understanding of the sequential or series resource commitments when there is
uncertainty in the operating environment. Key to the duo’s theory creation is the perception that
the selections lens “provide an economic sense for the behavioural stages of incremental
resource investment.” The scientists Hurry et al., (1992) discovered that the Japanese venture
capitalists seemed not to make smaller separate or sole investments, but a bigger portion of
investments, with an intention of capturing a wider array of future opportunities, that they
thought were a sustainable and consistent options strategy, basically a new technology. In his
part, McGrath (1997) supported a perception logic of options technology by fronting the concept
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 6
that companies can create amplifying pre-investments to influence the uncertainty to their own
benefit. In another paper, McGrath advanced the perception that entrepreneurial ingenuities and
projects can be perceived to be “real options” and further recommended that these are managed
through “real options” school of thought (1999). In congruent to many of these studies, Kogut
and Kulatilaka (for the years1994b, 2001 and the year 2003) targeted at integrating the real
options literature and the capabilities through proposing a concept that re lotions gives a heuristic
outlining of perceiving the competences as creating a framework to react to the impending
undefined openings.
Provided the interest of the strategy segment in studying and comprehending the true behaviours
of the companies, it is not unique that when paralleled to the research in the “real options” in the
economics as well as finance fields, the strategy studies have paid considerably more attention to
matters about the implementation of options (Rumelt et al., 1994). While the “real options
theory” can be plied in principle to appraise the strategic investment plus resources that are not
openly transacted, the strategy scientists have long proposed different challenges that can frame
both implementation and assessment. For example, repairs challenges, creation, and exercise. It
is true that the primary concept discovers its heritages in the original assistances in the area and
has run through the entire line of real options study in the investment strategy.
For instance, Kogut (1985) discussed the challenges faced by the company managers when
identifying the valuable alternatives attached in the company’s investments, a fact that is
likewise supported by Bowman & Hurry (in the year 1993 article). Additionally, just because a
company identifies with entrenched possibilities does not imply its availability of the
organizational and management structures to back up the enactment (Kogut, 1989). Additionally,
the executives may not utilize the appropriate data in assessing the “real options”, or may
evaluate them in a wrong way as for result of lack of suitable proxies (Miller & Shapira, 2004
Bowman & Moskowitz, 2001). Lastly, the organizational and managerial factors may further
change the exercise decision and option maintenance: the supervisors might be liable to
intensification of obligation, they might not adhere to the complex cues for exercise due to
bounded rationality (Coff and Laverty, 2001; Kogut, 1991; Adner and Levinthal, 2004; Garud,
Kumaraswamy, & Nayyar, 1998; McGrath, 1999;).
Significance of the ROT to Strategic Management
The “real options theory” avails a group of logical techniques as well as heuristics with the
intention of helping deal with and evaluate the uncertainties that pervade the strategic choices
(Kogut & Kulatilaka, 1994). Rumelt et al., in his research study recognized uncertainty as one of
the great 5 monkey ditches that motivated research deviating from the original “neoclassical
theory” of the company, and that has led to the emergence of the strategic management area.
(1994, p. 26). Given the important responsibility of uncertainty in regards to strategic choices
and decisions, it is more appropriate that the amplified significance of the “real options theory”
for strategic management can be justified by a minimum of three important influences, which
likewise explains why the “real options” are unique:
a) ROT calls for intensive investigation to relook into the received knowledge, and provides
special predictions on company’s decision for several categories of strategic decision
under conditions that are uncertain. Take a look at the following illustrations; as earlier
discussed, the real options angle challenges the conventional perspective of JVs (joint
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 7
ventures) like marriages, where stability and longevity were the primary success
indicators. According to real options theory, companies can open value at the JV
termination stage, and there is very important role played by the conventional
investments joint ventures by design angle. As a second example, the FDIs (foreign direct
investments) has for a long time been considered to be the answer to the transaction costs
that accompany the assets and market exchange technology. The real options theory, by
contrast, focuses more on the dynamic efficiency gains, the company’s capability to seize
the upside opportunities and downside risk reduction over time by changing the value
chain activities across different borders in response to the diverse uncertainties. Lastly, at
a more general degree, the real options issue new regulations for resource investment
through indicating that real options change a company’s investment threshold away from
the criteria of the NPV. While the thresholds details impact on the different real options
has been shown somewhere else, the provided insight by the real options analysis can be
summarized briefly in the following manner: a company may use a minimized investment
threshold & make a decision to invest even in a situation where the NPV is not positive.
Where the embedded growth option is sufficiently valuable; on the contrary, a company
may use an elevated investment threshold and make a decision not to put investment even
when the NPV is in good standing (positive NPV). Where the embedded or attached
deferral options are sufficient and the related opportunities costs of investing in the
present time are important.
b) The ROT suggests that an unbalanced payoff system for entrenched options investments
that real options allow companies to minimize the downside risks while evaluating the
upside opportunities Bowman & Hurry, 1993. The performance outcomes asymmetry is
as a result of the discretionary decisions right that options generate, for example, the right
to choose the results in the future only when it is favourable. When the real options are
compared to other theories, it gives the suggestion that the higher the level of the
uncertainty, the greater the potential payoffs to the holder of the option, given that the
very first investment is very limited (few options) and the downside losses are
constrained (Hull, 2003). Another important factor of the theory focuses on the flexibility
where there is uncertainty features the option value, and the said value can be responsible
for a significant part of the several investments value. Empirical findings and theory also
suggest that the value of such options significantly differs across companies and
industries. An important issue to consider in the case of the strategic management area is
that the heterogeneity sources may be (Tong & Reuer, 2006 and Kester, 1984).
c) Lastly, the real options theory provides the proof regarding the companies’ resource
allocation processes through informing strategic decision making. For a long time now,
strategic planning has embraced such issues as a follow-up opportunity, sequential
management of uncertainty and information, and incremental resource commitment,
which are all important for a company’s strategy. However, by their very nature, planning
frameworks lacked the type of strong decisions criteria as described and defined by the
investment models in the conventional finance theory. The real options theory can assist
in enhancing the strategic decision making for an organization by introducing the
discipline of the financial markets into the scientific planning tools, and also by
integrating the strategic realities into the conventional budgeting models that do not
account for their flexibility value explicitly and managed discretions (Amram &
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 8
Kulatilaka, 1999; Trigeorgis, 1996). While good implementation of the real options
analysis for resource allocation calls for overcoming the organization challenges, the real
options theory promises to integrate financial and strategic analyses for the corporate
strategy (Myers, 1984; Bettis, 1983).
Competitive Advantage of Firms as Seen in Realistic Real Theory
As will be observed in this segment, when it comes to implementation of these options, it is
argued that organizations may have differences in their implementation of the prior stated
factors. According to Myers in 1977, the current values of options account for the value an
organization, as an attempt to increase investments in the case of terms becoming more
favourable.
As stated by Kulatilaka and Kogut in 2001, the argument raised in past research is that these
favourable terms are accumulated in different processes that are imbued with a set of proprietary
“real options” on useful assets, which are readily available in factor markets, which identifies
how these terms are accumulated. The diversity of a firm may result from proprietary options, is
an assumption born of previous work. In 1996, Trigeorgis that in a situation whereby a myriad
of firms has equal portions of shared options, the theory developed will respond to this situation.
Accessibility to the feedback that comes in the form of novel information on the assets value and
contingent nature is brought about by a real option.
Table 1: Existing approaches to generating heterogeneity in factor markets that are compatible
with “real options theory”
How performance heterogeneity emerges
Differential endowments in real
options
Differential access to options allows a focal firm to
acquire assets in factor markets that other firms cannot
acquire.
Endowments in options (Barney,
1991; Kogut and Kulatilaka, 2001;
Myers, 1977).
Unique complementarities allow the firm to acquire
assets in factor markets because those assets are more
valuable to the focal firm than to other firms.
Productive complementarities
(Adegbesan, 2009; Lee, Folta, &
Lieberman, 2011; Lippman and
Rumelt, 2003).
Superior information allows the firm to more
accurately price an option on an asset and to generate
advantage in an otherwise complete market through
bidding or exercise.
Information (Barney, 1986;
Makadok and Barney, 2001;
Maritan & Florence, 2008).
Learning abilities such as integration of new information and practice of unforeseen claims on an
asset in a factor market differ from one firm to the next. These learning abilities are categorized
as updating of beliefs and processing of information. The imperativeness of implementing a real
option is emphasized by the idea of information processing. The raw data acquired from the
feedback received by the firm, as a result of implementing a real option, has to be converted into
usable information. Extant work in feedback learning is very similar to the ideology of belief
updating as suggested by both Levinthal and Posen in 2012.
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 9
Transaction Cost Theory
The 2009 Oliver Williamson’s Economics Nobel prize recognizes the importance of TCT Theory
(Transaction Costs Economics) for analysis of economic governance, specifically in the
company boundaries. TCT reinforced the effect of the awards in economics discipline in 1991
for Ronald Coarse’s work on the nature of the company that is considered seminal work for the
transaction cost economics. Transaction cost economics/ theory is essential in the analysis of a
number of organizational and strategic matters important to the company. Specifically, TCT has
been used in conducting studies on companies’ boundaries, the rationale for undertaking an
acquisition, vertical integration decisions, networks and other dynamic governance forms. TCT
has grown to cover international business and strategic management in making efforts to explain
how companies internationalize and the required structural management in enhancing the odds of
success.
Figure: Transaction Cost Theory
TCT attempts to justify why firms exist, and why firms expand or reasons why they source
activities to the external environment. The theory suggests that companies try to reduce the costs
of switching resources with the environment and that they try to reduce the bureaucratic costs of
the exchanges within the firm. Firms are as a result weighting the costs of switching resources with
the environment, against the bureaucratic costs of in-house performance activities.
The theory perceives market and institutions as different possible forms of coordinating and
organizing economic transactions. When the external transactional costs are higher compared to
the firm’s internal bureaucratic costs, the firm will experience growth, because the firm is in a
position to conduct its activities in a cheaper way, compared to when the activity redone in the
market. However, where the bureaucratic costs are higher compared to the external transaction
costs, then the company have to be downsized.
Core Competency by Kotler
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 10
A core competency is an idea in management theory created by Gary Hamel and C Kotler
Prahalad. The core competency theory is a harmonized mixture of several skills and resources
that distinguish company in a marketplace and therefore forms the foundation of the firm’s
competitiveness.
Core competencies meet three main criteria including:
a) Core competencies provide access to several markets
b) Core competencies should make a substantial contribution to the perceived consumer
benefits for the complete product
c) Core competencies are difficult to copy or imitate by competition
A company’s core competencies may include fine optics, precision electronics and
microelectronics. These help the company to build high-tech cameras better than the
competition, and at the same time can be used in manufacturing other products that require the
competencies. A core competency originates from a specific set of skills or methods of
production that deliver extra value to the consumer. The core competencies allow the company
to access a range of markets.
As part of TCT, core competency ensures organization success through strategic identification of
the market, ensuring production of a complete product and creation of a totally unique product in
the market.
VRIN /VRIO Analysis
Birger Wernerfelt in 1984 developed the resource-based view, abbreviated as RBV, as a
foundation for competitive advantage for a company that mainly relies on the use of a set of
valuable intangible or tangible resource at disposal of the company. The RBV theory has been
very influential and has gone further to form the basis for VRIO frameworks and other similar
models.
In Wernerfelt’s theory, the company is a set of resources. A business differs according to what
such resources are and how the resources are combined together. Examples of resources include
knowledge, information, assets, processes, attributes and capabilities.
Figure: VRIO Illustration
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 11
Not all business resources are strategically and equally relevant. Some resources, however,
provide the business with a competitive advantage. Such resources possess the VRIN
characteristics which can be identified by focusing on the following essential attributes;
i) Value: identifying resources that can bring the company value can be an invaluable
source of competitive advantage. However, some resources are easy to obtain, while
others are very costly and difficult to obtain.
ii) Rareness: resources that are t the disposal of every competitor does not add much
value, but highly scarce resources are a source of competitive advantage.
iii) Imitability; an ideal resource must not, and cannot be obtained by the competitors
iv) Non-substitutability; an ideal resource cannot be substituted by other resources
Asset Specificity
Asset specificity is a core component of TCT. Asset specificity is a major factor impacting on
the Transaction Cost in an organization. Asset specificity refers to the level at which an asset can
be used across multiple purposes and scenarios. A high-level specificity asset only has used in a
single situation or one purpose. On the other asset, a low specificity asset has multiple purposes
or uses. Asset specificity concept applies to the designed capital to feature one function or
trained labour targeted at performing a single task, and has its limited applications and uses due
to some inherent restrictions on other possible applications and uses. The more an asset is
specific in its functionality, the lower its redeployability or potential resale value. The
personalized computer applications are a perfect example of a highly specific asset. Generally,
the service sectors can be categorized as being of low asset specificity, on the other hand, the
airline industry can be categorized as being high asset specificity. It is high risk to invest in high
specificity assets when the economic conditions are uncertain or poor.
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 12
Table 1: Literature summary on determinants
There is also a concern when a specific asset is immobile. This is referred to as site specificity.
For instance, a given asset may be located in a specific place and it is prohibitively or impossibly
expensive to move. An example of a high site-specific company is where a manufacturing
company has its plants located in a given area and it is very expensive, impossible or very
difficult to relate it to another highly strategic location.
Asset specificity challenge: opportunistic pricing can be a serious challenge with the highly
specific asset. When a firm depends too much on a single supplier for a given parts supply, the
supplier may make efforts and tricks to charge unnecessarily high for the parts. The supplier may
also try to underpay the supplier on their part knowing too well that the supplier has another
market to supply their products. This problem can be effectively solved and prevented through a
properly written and nicely negotiated contracts prior tossup-ply.
Emotional Intelligence
There are stiull difficulty in measuring emotional intelligence. MacCann & Roberts, (2008) and
Dulewicz & Higgs, (2000) have engaged in comprehensive studies that helped outline theories of
measuring emotional intelligence, especially at place of work. However, the concept of
emotional intelligence (EI) is not a new one in workplace, since studies in the field began far
back as in the 1920s. Edward Thorndike first introduced the social intelligence concept in the
1920s, while making efforts to determine the factors that determine the predictability of IQ.
Edward’s theory suggests the social intelligence causes fluctuations in the outcome measures
which are not explanations for IQ. This implies that social intelligence does not depend on IQ.
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 13
Several theories about emotions in a company presents emotional status at work and important
determining factors of satisfaction and performance; and hence is adherence to Affective Events
Theory which depends on the emotional intelligence demand for a specific job where different
behaviors are created, leading to both negative and positive events (like autonomy, emotional
labor, tasks, hassles, demands etc.). these experiences then lead to different kinds of emotions at
place of work which impacts on the worker’s attitude., for instance, spontaneous help or
impulsive action. Such experiences are caused by individual tendencies like positive moods,
negative moods and emotional intelligence. This means that the emotions regulate and influences
a persons’ attitudes which are concerned with satisfaction and motivation, commitment and
loyalty, and also decisions regarding staying or quitting the job.
The link between realistic real options and competitive advantage
The first basis of starting the argument is over the delineation of a “real option” in the event of
both contemporaneous and prospective uncertainty, in giving meaning to this type of option. The
ratio of perspective and contemporaneous uncertainty and magnitude of the total uncertainty, are
the differences that may arise in the realistic real options.
Managerial flexibility is put at the top of a firm’s priority list as observed in the occurrence of
prospective uncertainty and the existence of contemporaneous uncertainty presents managerial
decision-making within a genuine “real option” as quintessential. The efficacy of firms when it
comes to implementing realistic “real options” differs in factor markets. These differences are
based on either the magnitude of the mistakes they make and the number of these mistakes,
implementation of alternatives that ought to have been put on hold or terminating possibilities
that ought to have been implemented. The three steps mentioned below will guide the direction
of our argument.
During the process of choosing an option exercise, differences in the articulation of a firm’s
subjective philosophies about the worth of the asset at the period in which the process of
choosing an option exercise was being conceived. Companies gifted with replicated selections
and acquiring identical data have different subjective beliefs as observed in our grafted feedback
learning discussion to real options.
These differences in firms may include:
a) Transformation of data into useable information- the ability of firms to transform data
into information differs in regulating and controlling the activity of processing
information as per the conditions set by the realistic real options.
b) Updating the belief process- the occurrence of a definite level of contemporaneous
uncertainty, due to the noisy new information, differences may arise in the capacity to
manage the conviction modernising procedure in various firms. A combination of these
mechanisms promotes the incorporation of new information, so as to lace a contingent
assertion on an asset.
c) The correctness of subjective beliefs- these alterations of the accurateness of individual
opinions bring about contrasting of the option implementation decisions, which in turn
causes errors in the option implementation. This also leads to the deviation of option
exercise decisions as an outcome of alterations in the latent value of an asset. Take for
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 14
example the occurrence of implementing an option that should have been eliminated in
exercising a realistic “real option” in asset acquisition in a factor market. This is as a
result of the exercise price exceeding the asset and the subjective belief being higher than
the exercise price. Or even in the case of a firm not indulging in acquisitions of assets as
an outcome of terminating the option in the factor market though it was required in
option execution.
d) The occurrence of competitive heterogeneity- this will happen due to option execution
errors made in the resource allocation practice and may even result to a competitive
advantage for the firm. Take for instance two organisations A and B, which have equal
shared realistic “real options” in the acquisition of industrious assets in factor markets.
Executives are the main people that are engaged in the option-exercising decision-making
procedure. Minimization of costs incurred by a firm is brought about by assets by a
significant fixed margin.
The right moment for a firm to exercise its identified option is when the cost reduced is higher
than the exercise price, in assets acquisition. And resulting errors from option exercising, lead to
an increase in competitive advantage e.g. due to the differences in beliefs on asset value amid
institutions A and B causes A to exercise its realistic options in asset procurement in the factor
market even if it should have been terminated as soon as firm B had terminated its realistic real
option, which offers company B a competitive advantage over A.
Table 2: Extant theories that are grafted onto our behavioral real option theory
Real Options
Strategic Factor
Markets
Feedback
Learning
Real Options
Valuation
Real Options
Reasoning
Quantifies the
value of
managerial
flexibility.
Highlights the
value of
managerial
flexibility.
Information
imperfections can lead
to competitive
heterogeneity.
A behaviorally
realistic model of
decision-making.
Newly arrived
information
resolves
prospective
uncertainty that
existed in the
past.
Newly arrived
information
resolves
prospective
uncertainty that
existed in the past
Imperfect nature of
information regarding
the current value of
assets.
The ability to learn
(resolve
uncertainty) as
information arrives
that updates asset
value.
Assumption of
perfect
information on
the
contemporaneous
value of an asset.
Inability to
compare or
ordinally rank the
payoffs to
alternative
projects.
Does not explicitly
recognize the arrival of
new information over
time and learning is
assumed to be trivial.
Does not
(formally) model
changes in asset
value.
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 15
Conclusively, the differences in option implementation decisions in factor markets are as a result
of a diversified information process and belief updates, and may also bring about competitive
advantage.
These ideas emanate from our theory of realistic real options theory.
Contemporaneous uncertainty also influences the realistic real options as prospective
uncertainties do. This is due to the data provided by a realistic real option about the asset rather
than provide distinct information. Engagement of a firm in transforming the data acquired from
the realistic real option into useable information is paramount in information processing
activities.
The level of contemporaneous uncertainty reduces as the efficacy of processing information
increases in any particular body of data. Which simply means, that the information acquired from
the decision-making process of the option to be executed by a firm, will bear less noise and will
be useable. As a result of various differences in the traits of top management personnel, problem-
solving schedules, and the firm’s organizational structure, there will be the presence of
differences in the information processing capability of firms relative to realistic real option.
The firms with high information processing capacity will definitely have a lower
contemporaneous uncertainty as compared to those with lower processing capacities.
First proposition: contemporaneous uncertainty reduces the superior level of information
processing rise, competitive advantage created by a firm through increasing efficacy of executing
real options in factor markets. From an adaptive angle, their rationality is intentional. This is due
to the efforts put by a firm to transform raw data into usable information and implementing this
information as an attempt to exercise their decision. As mentioned in the earlier sections,
Bayesian learning is embedded with the notion that most firms proportionally update its beliefs
on asset value. Depending on the amount of noise emanating from the contemporaneous
uncertainty of the new information, the extent to which a firm updates its beliefs varies.
Second proposition: the ability of a firm to competitive advantage by “real options” in factor
markets is brought about by maintaining a belief-updating rate that equals that the level of
contemporaneous uncertainty.
Conclusively, we propose that challenges facing belief updating should interact with the
problems of information processing. As the financial option, which lacks contemporaneous
uncertainty, the asset value is easily determined due to the dearth of noise in information
processing.
On the other hand, high contemporaneous uncertainty, the signal will lack information and will
have a lot of noise, which will render any information acquired null and void. When firms are
processing information with an average efficacy, means that the contemporaneous uncertainty
will be at a moderate level which in turn will lead to the belief updating becoming difficult.
Third proposition: The relationship between a company’s capacity to create competitive
advantage through efficiently terminating “real options” in the factor market and the firm’s
ability to equalize the belief-updating frequency to the levels of contemporaneous uncertainty.
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 16
Other Realistic Real Options Consequences
Contemporary research on organization structure, cognition, and challenge solution has linked to
our theory, in this segment. As suggested by both Burgelman and Bower in 1983 and 1970
respectively, managerial and organizational processes facilitate the generation of competitive
advantage.
According to Mason and Hambrick in 1984, the top management team (TMT) is directly
responsible for the amount of attention accorded to the perception of processing data. From
previous research on this topic, education, organizational tenure, and age are characteristics of
TMT that are associated with TMT demographics for underlying cognitive processes, as
supported by Tihanyi, Ellstrand, Dalton, and Daily in 2000. These TMT characteristics were
found to have measures of variations, by other works that were associated with decision-making,
as proposed by Wiersema and Bantel in 1992. As contemporaneous uncertainty levels rise, TMT
members who learn in noisy areas are not prone to make option execution errors.
The older lot of TMT members will take a longer time to update their beliefs than their younger
counterparts, which makes the younger lot more prone to making option execution errors in
noisy areas, which slow down the updating rate. For instance, Bingham, Davis, and Eisenhardt in
2009, stated that it is vital to recognize and inspect the various differences between the cognitive
capability of TMT in decision-making and how they affect an organization’s decision-making
process, which was further supported by Gavetti in 2012, who also gave the meaning of
behavioral failures as the factors that hinder a firm’s ability to acquire resources as other firms
can, and TMT members are to blame for these type of failures due to their mental plasticity,
rationality and discerning ability. After examining these cognitive and behaviour-based
approaches and integrating them with the propositions of this research paper, facilitates the
deduction of links between a myriad of option execution errors, mind assessments and the
generation of an advantage.
According to Fredrick in 2005, calculative skills are connected to the cognitive reflection test,
through the work in behavioural economics. The TMT members who pass the cognitive
reflection assessment will be in a better position to make appropriate decisions, make minor
option execution errors and create a competitive advantage over other firms led by TMT
members who failed the test.
In 2008, Mackey suggested that through linking both the circumstances surrounding option
execution in a factor market and contingency for noticed variations in TMT members and
organization value. More generally, our work provides a circumstance-contingent explanation for
observed differences between individual TMT members and firm value (e.g., Mackey, 2008).
Entrepreneurial confidence literature by Lowe and Ziedonis in 2006, is an example of a research
source in which biases are conspicuous. This literature also suggests that decisions such as entry
and delayed exit are positively influenced by confidence, after controlling for context and ability.
According to this research, resource allocation and generation of competitive advantage depend
on the ability of managers to overcome cognitive biases such as hubris.
The propositions in this research advocate for the creation of various ways of executing options
by managers, after dealing with being either over confident or under confident, which will also
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 17
improve the belief updating rate. Dunkelberg, Woo, and Cooper in 1988 suggested that linking
of responses from several surveys pertaining individual bias would provide a chance for
experimental research. Examination of victims of individual bias has a probability of making or
not making errors when deciding on the exercise options in factor markets.
The difference in the ability of organizational structures to consolidate and process information
has been noticed for a long time. According to Rivkin and Siggelkow in 2005, information
processing is interactively affected by decision rights and tasks allocation, alignment of
incentives, and interactions. And this research aims at emphasizing on how these factors affect
information processing. Nadler and Tushman in 1978 stated that the task environment influences
the efficacy of a particular firm. And the nature and efficacy of decisions are impacted by a
firm’s hierarchical breadth, size, and depth, as supported by Stiglitz and Sah in 1986. Similarly,
belief updating may be affected by the structured processes that minimize unfairness (Chugh,
Milkman, and Bazerman, 2009).
According to Lovallo and Kahneman in 1993, attempted emancipation from certain situations
that a firm’s current problem emanates from, is a way of promoting organizational success. Our
research has also sourced information on several plausible channels, from insights acquired from
organization structure work. Dividing the top management authority in an attempt to delegate
decision-making will negatively affect the processing of information since this increases the odds
of making errors when deciding to execute options in factor markets. This also prohibits the
creation of competitive advantage through exercising real options. Number of levels that a
portion of data must cover before the decision-making process is over, influences the efficiency
of processing information by a firm.
Another factor that affects the efficacy of processing information is the span of control of a firm,
those that use a vertical span of control will experience a reduced rate of belief updates. Our
solution to this challenge according to our research, is to increase the interaction of the number
of vertical levels in management and the contemporaneous uncertainty level, which in turn will
better explain its relationship with the likelihood of making errors when executing options in
factor markets.
Conclusively, the rapidly growing challenge creation and challenge solving literature are
impacted by our research.
According to Zenger and Nickerson in 2004, the manner in which a firm formulate and attempt
to come up with a solution, is influenced by the level of challenge solving skills. Firms are
encouraged to take note of their differences in incentive magnitude, conflict resolution programs,
so as to enable them to offer a solution to these challenges.
The optimal form of search is compromised by these organizational problems that influence the
appropriation of knowledge and accumulation of strategic information, also stated by Zenger and
Nickerson in 2004.
Balancing of these ideas through assessment of the relationship between the utilization of various
processes of formulating problems, constituents of the organization structure, and execution
mistakes in real options are made possible through our theory.
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 18
For example, knowledge accumulation and appropriation may be affected by the use of open and
Concord-based challenge frames, which leads to complications with the execution of options.
In the same light, the manner in which personnel communicates with each other greatly affects
the process of transforming raw data into information and also extends to the execution of real
options.
Conclusions
The main focus of this paper is to delve into the theory of realistic real options and its
effectiveness in making decisions on resource allocation in factor markets considered to be
strategic. We also identify and evaluate both the prospective and contemporaneous uncertainties,
which covers the value of assets currently and upcoming values.
The decisions made on resource allocation, which through contemporaneous uncertainties,
managers within the firm and as a whole can acquire a competitive heterogeneity, are related to
the exercise of options in factor markets. The premise of our theory is based on the studies done
by Bromiley, Maritan, Burgelman, and Bower in 1986, 2001, 1983, and 1970 respectively, that
asserted that structural, behavioural, and organizational differences, result from competitive
heterogeneity, in the resource allocation process.
Specifically argued out by Burgelman, Bower and other various management professionals, was
that differences in the allocation of decision rights, knowledge, and power, birthed the
differences in the firms’ ability to control the uncertainty experienced in the surrounding
investments.
Our contribution to the research suggested that competitive advantage can be better understood
by expounding on the extent to which values of real options have on the processing of
information by a firm. The alterations in asset values over a period, evolution and emergence of
heterogeneity are better explained by drafting a factor market and feedback learnt from
previously stated theories. The significance of variations in the internal structure of a firm in
updating of beliefs or processing information is evident, especially when compared to previous
research expounding on the differences in options, information or even productive
complementarities. Just as most research papers have limitations, so does ours, but does not fall
short of providing a commencement point for discussion.
The first thing observed is the noticing of real options lens as an undeveloped tool to observe
resource allocation decisions. Real options are risked at becoming inappropriate in the event of
limitations in prospective uncertainty which makes it harder to invest in a series of sequences.
Other valuation approaches can be implemented in a setting whereby a certain firm is
undertaking a myriad of projects, such as the portfolio theory.
The second thing observed is the assumption made, that most of the resource constraints facing
actual firms are not factored in. Planned acquisitions, willingness to alter debt levels, liquidity
and the desire for investment are the constraints that undermine investments made in relation to
behavioural approach (Bromiley, 1986). These constraints inhibit the exploration of lucrative
investment opportunities, and exact force on top management when deciding on a potentially
promising venture of uncertain value by firms.
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 19
Our research paper has achieved realism through evaluating the role and consequences of
informational fallibilities and the limitations undermining productive opportunities for future
study. Also suggested in this research paper is that when the contemporaneous uncertainty levels
are high, not much thought is given to the prospective uncertainty levels, since they are irrelevant
at this point. According to Teach in 2003, the low number of firms adopting real options in
exercise is caused by the neglect of prospective uncertainty.
This unwillingness may also be attributed to managers’ avoiding real option tools that they
consider to be usable in the finance facet options, which lacks contemporaneous uncertainty and
functionality is minimal in the real world. According to Van Putten and MacMillan in 2004,
projects that have high levels of uncertainty should be avoided by managers, as a bid to follow
the advice derived from proponents of real options. It is important to note that it is
contemporaneous uncertainty that causes a manager not to invest in a project, rather than the
prospective uncertainty.
When drafting this research paper, we sought to expound on the resource allocation process and
how it brings about competitive advantage and heterogeneity, as an attempt to provide this
theory in a simple and comprehensible way. We recommend that it would be beneficial to
implement belief updating, information processing and finally, resource allocation decisions into
firms so as to develop plausible behavioural and organizational activities.
We believe that we couldn’t have come up with a better channel through which current and
future organization scholars can infer from this approach.
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 20
Reference List
Adner, R., & Levinthal, D. A. 2004a. Real options and real tradeoffs. Academy of Management
Review, 29(1): 120126.
Adner, R., & Levinthal, D. A. 2004b. What is not a real option: Considering boundaries for the
application of real options to business strategy. Academy of Management Review, 29(1):
74 85.
Amram, M., & Kulatilaka, N. 1999. Disciplined decisions: Aligning strategy with the financial
markets. Harvard Business Review, 77(1): 95104.
Bantel, K. A., & Jackson, S. E. 1989. Top management and innovations in banking: Does the
composition of the top team make a difference? Strategic Management Journal, 10: 107
124.
Barney, J. 1986. Strategic factor markets: Expectations, luck, and business strategy. Management
Science, 32(10): 12311241.
Barney, J. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management,
17(1): 99120.
Black, F., & Scholes, M. 1973. The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. The Journal of
Political Economy, 81(3): 637654.
Bower, J. 1970. Managing the Resource Allocation Process. Cambridge: Harvard Business
Press.
Bowman, E. H., & Hurry, D. 1987. Strategic options. Working Paper 87-20, Reginald H. Jones
Center, Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania.
Brealey, R., Myers, S., & Allen, F. 2010. Principles of Corporate Finance, 10th Edition. New
York: McGraw-Hill Irwin.
Bromiley, Philip (1986), ‘Corporate planning and capital investment’, Journal of Economic
Behavior & Organization, 7 (2), 147-70.
Burgelman, R. A. 1983. A process model of internal corporate venturing in the diversified major
firm. Administrative Science Quarterly, 28(2): 223.
Cooper, A. C., Woo, C. Y., & Dunkelberg, W. C. 1988. Entrepreneurs' perceived chances for
success. Journal of Business Venturing, 3(2): 97108.
Davis, G. B., & Olson, M. 1985. Management Information Systems: Conceptual Foundations,
Methods and Development. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Davis, J. P., Eisenhardt, K. M., & Bingham, C. B. 2009. Optimal structure, market dynamism,
and the strategy of simple rules. Administrative Science Quarterly, 54(3): 413452.
Denrell, J., Fang, C., & Winter, S. G. 2003. The economics of strategic opportunity. Strategic
Management Journal, 24(10): 977990.
Denrell, J., & March, J. 2001. Adaptation as information restriction: The hot stove effect.
Organization Science, 12(5): 523538.
Dixit, A. 1989. Entry and exit decisions under uncertainty. Journal of Political Economy, 97(3):
620638.
Dixit, A., & Pindyck, R. 1994. Investment Under Uncertainty. Princeton: Princeton University
Press. Felin, T., & Foss, N. 2005. Strategic organization: A field in search of micro-
foundations. Strategic Organization, 3(4): 441455.
Foss, N. 2011. Invited editorial: Why micro-foundations for resource-based theory are needed
and what they may look like. Journal of Management, 37(5): 14131428.
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 21
Foss, N. J., & Klein, P. G. 2005. Entrepreneurship and the economic theory of the firm: Any
gains from trade? In Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research, International Handbook
Series on Entrepreneurship (Vol. 2, pp. 5580). New York: Springer US.
Foss, N. J., Klein, P. G., Kor, Y. Y., & Mahoney, J. T. 2008. Entrepreneurship, subjectivism, and
the resource-based view: Toward a new synthesis. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal,
2(1): 7394.
Gavetti, G. 2012. PerspectiveToward a Behavioral Theory of Strategy. Organization Science,
23(1): 267285.
Gavetti, G., & Levinthal, D. 2000. Looking forward and looking backward: Cognitive and
experiential search. Administrative Science Quarterly, 45(1): 113137.
Hambrick, D. C., & Mason, P. A. 1984. Upper echelons: The organization as a reflection of its
top managers. Academy of Management Review, 9(2): 193206.
Kahneman, D., & Lovallo, D. 1993. Timid choices and bold forecasts: A cognitive perspective
on risk taking. Management Science, 39(1): 1731.
Kogut, B. 1991. Joint ventures and the option to expand and acquire. Management Science, 37:
1933.
Kogut, B., & Kulatilaka, N. 2001. Capabilities as Real Options. Organization Science, 12(6):
744 758.
Kogut, B., & Kulatilaka, N. 2004. Real options pricing and organizations: The contingent risks
of extended theoretical domains. Academy of Management Review, 29(1): 102110.
Lippman, S. A., & Rumelt, R. P. 1982. Uncertain imitability: An analysis of interfirm differences
in efficiency under competition. The Bell Journal of Economics, 13(2): 418.
Lippman, S. A., & Rumelt, R. P. 2003. A bargaining perspective on resource advantage.
Strategic Management Journal, 24(11): 10691086.
Lowe, R. A., & Ziedonis, A. A. 2006. Overoptimism and the performance of entrepreneurial
firms. Management Science, 52(2): 173186.
Luehrman, T. A. 1998. Investment opportunities as real options: Getting started on the numbers.
Harvard Business Review, 76(4): 5167.
Mackey, A. 2008. The effect of CEOs on firm performance. Strategic Management Journal,
29(12): 13571367.
Mahoney, J. T., & Qian, L. 2013. Market frictions as building blocks of an organizational
economics approach to strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, 34: 1019
1041.
Makadok, R. 2001. Toward a synthesis of the resource-based and dynamic-capability views of
rent. Strategic Management Journal, 22: 387401.
Makadok, R., & Barney, J. B. 2001. Strategic factor market intelligence: An application of
information economics to strategy formulation and competitor intelligence. Management
Science, 47(12): 16211638.
Maritan, C. A. 2001. Capital investment as investing in organizational capabilities: An
empirically grounded process model. Academy Of Management Journal, 44(3): 513531.
Maritan, C. A., & Alessandri, T. M. 2007. Capabilities, real options, and the resource allocation
process. In J. Reuer & T. W. Tong (Eds.), Advances in Strategic Management (Vol. 24,
pp. 307332). Emerald Group Publishing Limited.
Maritan, C. A., & Florence, R. E. 2008. Investing in capabilities: bidding in strategic factor
markets with costly information. Managerial and Decision Economics, 29: 227239.
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 22
Maritan, C.A., & M.A. Peteraf. 2011. Building a Bridge Between Resource Acquisition and
Resource Accumulation. Journal of Management, 37(5) 1374-1389.
McDonald, R., & Siegel, D. 1986. The value of waiting to invest. Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 101(4): 707728.
McGrath, R. G. 1997. A real options logic for initiating technology positioning investments.
Academy of Management Review, 22(4): 974996.
Merton, R. C. 1998. Applications of option-pricing theory: Twenty-five years later. American
Economic Review, 88(3): 323349.
Milkman, K. L., Chugh, D., & Bazerman, M. H. 2009. How can decision making be improved?
Perspectives on Psychological Science, 4(4): 379383.
Myers, S. C. 1977. Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics, 5:
147 175.
Nickerson, J. A., & Zenger, T. R. 2004. A knowledge-based theory of the firmThe problem-
solving perspective. Organization Science, 15(6): 617632.
Nickerson, J., Yen, C. J., & Mahoney, J. T. 2012. Exploring the problem-finding and problem-
solving approach for designing organizations. The Academy of Management Perspectives,
26(1): 5272.
Peteraf, M. A. 1993. The cornerstones of competitive advantage: A resource-based view.
Strategic Management Journal, 14(3): 179191.
Peteraf, M., & Barney, J. 2003. Unraveling the resource-based tangle. Managerial and Decision
Economics, 24(4): 309.
Posen, H. E., Leiblein, M. J., & Chen, J. S. 2016. A behavioral theory of real options. Working
Paper.
Posen, H. E., & Levinthal, D. A. 2012. Chasing a moving target: Exploitation and exploration in
dynamic environments. Management Science, 58(3): 587-601
Rumelt, R., Schendel, D., & Teece, D. 1991. Strategic management and economics. Strategic
Management Journal, 12: 529.
Sah, R. K., & Stiglitz, J. E. 1986. The architecture of economic systems: Hierarchies and
polyarchies. American Economic Review, 76(4): 716727
Sakhartov, A. V., & Folta, T. B. 2014. Resource relatedness, redeployability, and firm value.
Strategic Management Journal, 35(12): 17811797.
Sakhartov, A. V., & Folta, T. B. 2015. Getting beyond relatedness as a driver of corporate value.
Strategic Management Journal, 36(13): 19391959.
Schmidt, J. 2014. Experience, experimentation and judgment: Towards a process theory of
entrepreneurial discovery (Vol. 2014, p. 15144). Presented at the Academy of
Management Proceedings.
Schmidt, J., & Keil, T. 2013. What Makes a Resource Valuable? Identifying the Drivers of Firm-
Idiosyncratic Resource Value. Academy of Management Review, 38(2): 206228.
Siggelkow, N., & Rivkin, J. W. 2005. Speed and search: Designing organizations for turbulence
and complexity. Organization Science, 16(2): 101122.
Simon, H. A. 1947. Administrative Behavior; A Study of Decision-Making Processes in
Administrative Organization. Oxford, England: Macmillan.
Simon, H. A. 1973. The structure of ill structured problems. Artificial Intelligence, 4(3): 181
201.
Simon, H. A. 1990. Invariants of human behavior. Annual Review of Psychology, 41: 119.
Teach, E. 2003. Will real options take root. CFO magazine, 19(9): 7375.
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 23
Tihanyi, L., Ellstrand, A. E., Daily, C. M., & Dalton, D. R. 2000. Composition of the top
management team and firm international diversification. Journal of Management, 26(6):
11571177.
Trigeorgis, L. 1996. Real Options: Managerial Flexibility and Strategy in Resource Allocation.
Cambridge: MIT press.
Trigeorgis, L., & Ioulianou, S. 2013. Valuing a high-tech growth company: The case of EchoSta
Communications Corporation. The European Journal of Finance, 19(7-8): 734759.
Trigeorgis, L., & Reuer, J. Real options theory in strategic management. Strategic Management
Journal, (Forthcoming).
Tushman, M. L., & Nadler, D. A. 1978. Information processing as an integrating concept in
organizational design. Academy of Management Review, 3(3): 613624.
Van Putten, A. B., & MacMillan, I. C. 2004. Making real options really work. Harvard Business
Review, 82(12): 134142.
Wiersema, M. F., & Bantel, K. A. 1992. Top management team demography and corporate
strategic change. Academy Of Management Journal, 35(1): 91121.
Wiersema, M. F., & Bantel, K. A. 1993. Top management team turnover as an adaptation
mechanism: The role of the environment. Strategic Management Journal, 14(7): 485
504.
Berger, P. G., Ofek, E., & Swary, I. (1996). Investor valuation of the abandonment option. Journal
of Financial Economics, 42, 257287.
Bernardo, A. E., & Chowdhry, B. (2002). Resources, real options, and corporate strategy. Journal
of Financial Economics, 63, 211234.
Bettis, R. (1983). Modern financial theory, corporate strategy and public policy: Three conun-
drums. Academy of Management Review, 8, 406415.
Brennan, M. J., & Schwartz, E. S. (1985). Evaluating natural resource investments. Journal of
Business, 58, 135157.
Chi, T. (2000). Option to acquire or divest a joint venture. Strategic Management Journal, 21, 665
687.
Childs, P. D., & Triantis, A. J. (1999). Dynamic R&D investment policies. Management Science,
45, 13591377.
Coff, R. W., & Laverty, K. J. (2001). Real options on knowledge assets: Panacea or Pandora’s
box? Business Horizons, 44(6), 2001, 7379.
Folta, T. B. (1998). Governance and uncertainty: The tradeoff between administrative control and
commitment. Strategic Management Journal, 19, 10071028.
Folta, T. B., Johnson, D. R., & O’Brien, J. P. (2006). Irreversibility, uncertainty, and the likelihood
of entry: An empirical assessment of the option to defer. Journal of Economic Behavior
and Organization, 61, 432452.
Folta, T. B., & Miller, K. D. (2002). Real options and equity partnerships. Strategic Man-agement
Journal, 23, 7788.
Folta, T. B., & O’Brien, J. P. (2004). Entry in the presence of dueling options. Strategic
Management Journal, 25, 121138.
Garud, R., Kumaraswamy, A., & Nayyar, P. (1998). Real options or fool’s gold? Perspective
makes the difference. Academy of Management Review, 23, 212214.
Grenadier, S. R. (2000). Game choices: The interaction of real options and game theory. London:
Risk Books.
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 24
Hayes, R. H., & Garvin, D. A. (1982). Managing as if tomorrow mattered. Harvard Business
Review, 60(May/June), 7079.
Hull, J. C. (2003). Options, futures, and other derivative securities. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-
Hall.
Hurry, D., Miller, A. T., & Bowman, E. H. (1992). Calls on high-technology: Japanese ex-
ploration of venture capital investments in the United States. Strategic Management
Journal, 13, 85101.
Kester, W. C. (1984). Today’s options for tomorrow’s growth. Harvard Business Review,
62(March/April), 153160.
Kogut, B. (1983). Foreign direct investment as a sequential process. In: C. P. Kindleberger & D.
B. Audretsch (Eds), The Multinational Corporation in the 1980s. Boston, MA: MIT Press.
Kogut, B. (1985). Designing global strategies: Profiting from operational flexibility. Sloan
Management Review, 27(1), 2738
Kogut, B. (1989). A note on global strategies. Strategic Management Journal, 10, 383389. Kogut,
B. (1991). Joint ventures and the option to expand and acquire. Management Science, 37,
1933.
Kogut, B., & Chang, S. J. (1996). Platform investments and volatile exchange rates: Direct
investment in the U.S. by Japanese electronic companies. Review of Economics and
Statistics, 78, 221231.
Kogut, B., & Kulatilaka, N. (1994a). Options thinking and platform investments: Investing in
opportunity. California Management Review, 36(2), 5271.
Kogut, B., & Kulatilaka, N. (1994b). Operating flexibility, global manufacturing, and the option
value of a multinational network. Management Science, 40, 123139.
Kogut, B., & Kulatilaka, N. (2001). Capabilities as real options. Organization Science, 12, 744
758.
Kogut, B., & Kulatilaka, N. (2003). Strategy, heuristics, and real options. In: D. Faulkner & A.
Campbell (Eds), The Oxford handbook of strategy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Kogut, B., & Kulatilaka, N. (2004). Real options pricing and organizations: The contin-gent risks
of extended theoretical domains. Academy of Management Review, 29, 102110
Kulatilaka, N., & Perotti, E. (1998). Strategic growth options. Management Science, 44, 1021
1031.
Lippman, S. A., & Rumelt, R. P. (1982). Uncertain imitability: An analysis of interfirm differ-
ences in efficiency under competition. Bell Journal of Economics, 13, 418438.
Luehrman, T. A. (1998). Strategy as a portfolio of real options. Harvard Business Review, 76(5),
8999.
Mahoney, J. T. (2005). The Economic Foundations of Strategy. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage
Publications.
Majd, S., & Pindyck, R. S. (1989). Learning curves and optimal production under uncertainty.
Rand Journal of Economics, 20, 331343.
Mason, S. P., & Merton, R. C. (1985). The role of contingent claims analysis in corporate finance.
In: E. Altman & M. Subrahmanyam (Eds), Recent advances in corporate finance.
Homewood, IL: Richard D. Inin.
Matsusaka, J. G. (2001). Corporate diversification, value maximization, and organizational
capabilities. The Journal of Business, 74, 409431.
McDonald, R. L., & Siegel, D. R. (1985). Investment and the valuation of firms when there is an
option to shut down. International Economic Review, 26, 331349.
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 25
McGrath, R. G. (1997). A real options logic for initiating technology positioning investments.
Academy of Management Review, 22, 974996.
McGrath, R. G. (1999). Falling forward: Real options reasoning and entrepreneurial failure.
Academy of Management Review, 24, 1330.
McGrath, R. G., Ferrier, W. J., & Mendelow, A. (2004). Real options as engines of choice and
heterogeneity. Academy of Management Review, 29, 86101.
Merton, R. C. (1973). Theory of rational option pricing. Bell Journal of Economics and
Management Science, 4, 141183.
Miller, K. D., & Folta, T. B. (2002). Option value and entry timing. Strategic Management Journal,
23, 655665.
Miller, K. D., & Reuer, J. J. (1998a). Asymmetric corporate exposures to foreign exchange rate
changes. Strategic Management Journal, 19, 11831191.
Miller, K. D., & Reuer, J. J. (1998b). Firm strategy and economic exposures to foreign exchange
rate movements. Journal of International Business Studies, 29, 493513.
Miller, K. D., & Shapira, Z. (2004). An empirical test of heuristics and biases affecting real option
valuation. Strategic Management Journal, 25, 269284.
Moel, A., & Tufano, P. (2002). When are real options exercised? An empirical study of mine
closings. Review of Financial Studies, 15, 3564.
Myers, S. C. (1977). Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics, 5,
147175.
Myers, S. C. (1984). Finance theory and financial strategy. Interfaces, 14, 126137. Pacheco-de-
Almeida, G., & Zemsky, P. (2003). The effect of time-to-build on strategic invest-ment
under uncertainty. Rand Journal of Economics, 34, 166182.
Paddock, J., Siegel, D., & Smith, J. (1988). Option valuation of claims on real assets: The case of
offshore petroleum leases. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103, 479508.
Pindyck, R. S. (1988). Irreversible investment, capacity choice, and the value of the firm.
American Economic Review, 78, 969985
Pindyck, R. S. (1991). Irreversibility, uncertainty, and investment journal of economic liter-ature.
Journal of Economic Literature, 29, 11101148.
Quigg, L. (1993). Empirical testing of real option-pricing models. Journal of Finance, 48, 621
640.
Reuer, J. J., & Leiblein, M. J. (2000). Downside risk implications of multinationality and
international joint ventures. Academy of Management Journal, 43, 203214.
Reuer, J. J., & Tong, T. W. (2005). Real options in international joint ventures. Journal of
Management, 31, 403423.
Reuer, J. J., & Tong, T. W. (2007). Corporation investments and growth options. Managerial and
Decision Economics, 28, forthcoming.
Roberts, K., & Weitzman, M. L. (1981). Funding criteria for research, development, and
exploration projects. Econometrica, 49, 12611288.
Rumelt, R. P., Schendel, D. E., & Teece, D. J., (Eds). (1994). Fundamental issues in strategy: A
research agenda. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.
Schwartz, E. S., & Trigeorgis, L. (2001). Real options and investment under uncertainty: An
overview. In: E. S. Schwartz & L. Trigeorgis (Eds), Real options and investment under
uncertainty: Classical readings and recent contributions. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Smit, H. T. J., & Trigeorgis, L. (2004). Strategic investment: Real options and games. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press
Resource Allocation in Strategic Factors 26
Tang, C. Y., & Tikoo, S. (1999). Operational flexibility and market valuation of earnings Strategic
Management Journal, 20, 749761
Titman, S. (1985). Urban land prices under uncertainty. American Economic Review, 75, 505
514.
Tong, T. W., & Reuer, J. J. (2006). Firm and industry influences on the value of growth options.
Strategic Organization, 4, 7195.
Tong, T. W., & Reuer, J. J. (2007). Real options in multinational corporations: Organizational
challenges and risk implications. Journal of International Business Studies, 38, 213230.
Tong, T. W., Reuer, J. J., & Peng, M. W. (2008). International joint ventures and the value of
growth options. Academy of Management Journal, 50, forthcoming.
Triantis, A. J. (2005). Realizing the potential of real options: Does theory meet practice? Journal
of Applied Corporate Finance, 17(2), 816.
Triantis, A. J., & Hodder, J. E. (1990). Valuing flexibility as a complex option. Journal of Finance,
45, 549565.
Trigeorgis, L. (1993). The nature of option interactions and the valuation of investments with
multiple real options. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 28, 120.
Trigeorgis, L. (1996). Real options: Managerial flexibility and strategy in resource allocation.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Place new order. It's free, fast and safe

-+
550 words

Our customers say

Customer Avatar
Jeff Curtis
USA, Student

"I'm fully satisfied with the essay I've just received. When I read it, I felt like it was exactly what I wanted to say, but couldn’t find the necessary words. Thank you!"

Customer Avatar
Ian McGregor
UK, Student

"I don’t know what I would do without your assistance! With your help, I met my deadline just in time and the work was very professional. I will be back in several days with another assignment!"

Customer Avatar
Shannon Williams
Canada, Student

"It was the perfect experience! I enjoyed working with my writer, he delivered my work on time and followed all the guidelines about the referencing and contents."

  • 5-paragraph Essay
  • Admission Essay
  • Annotated Bibliography
  • Argumentative Essay
  • Article Review
  • Assignment
  • Biography
  • Book/Movie Review
  • Business Plan
  • Case Study
  • Cause and Effect Essay
  • Classification Essay
  • Comparison Essay
  • Coursework
  • Creative Writing
  • Critical Thinking/Review
  • Deductive Essay
  • Definition Essay
  • Essay (Any Type)
  • Exploratory Essay
  • Expository Essay
  • Informal Essay
  • Literature Essay
  • Multiple Choice Question
  • Narrative Essay
  • Personal Essay
  • Persuasive Essay
  • Powerpoint Presentation
  • Reflective Writing
  • Research Essay
  • Response Essay
  • Scholarship Essay
  • Term Paper
We use cookies to provide you with the best possible experience. By using this website you are accepting the use of cookies mentioned in our Privacy Policy.